The Supreme Court's 'Bartleby' redistricting decision

I would prefer not to.” That was the invariable reply of the title character of Herman Melville’s 1853 story “Bartleby, the Scrivener,” when asked by his employer to perform a task.

It’s also a phrase you might use to describe the opinion of the Supreme Court in its latest redistricting (or gerrymandering) case, Gill v. Whitford. This was expected to be a closely divided case and one which many observers hoped would establish a clear legal standard to overturn partisan gerrymanders. But all nine justices concurred in the central point of Chief Justice John Roberts’s opinion that the plaintiffs lacked standing — harm “in a personal and individual way” — needed to bring the case. Evidently they “would prefer not to” resolve the issue of when partisan district-drawing violates voters’ constitutional rights.

It’s an issue the court first grappled with in 1973, less than a decade after its 1964 decisions requiring equal-population congressional and legislative districts.

Back then, the court conceded that redistricting “inevitably has and is intended to have substantive political consequences.” And when examining an obviously partisan Republican districting plan in Pennsylvania in 2004, eight justices were deadlocked 4-4, while Justice Anthony Kennedy found a constitutional violation but no remedy.

“There are yet no agreed upon substantive principles of fairness in districting,” he wrote then. And his concurrence in Gill v. Whitford suggests he hasn’t found any in the intervening 14 years.

The plaintiffs, Wisconsin Democrats who thought they’d found such a principle, must be disappointed. Their theory was that a districting plan should give each party the proportion of legislative seats identical to its proportion of the total votes for legislative statewide. They objected that Republican map-makers had prevented this by “packing” (putting too many Democrats in some districts) and “cracking” (putting just enough Republicans to win in some districts). They complained that this left many Democrats’ votes “wasted.”

There are some obvious problems here. For example, not all Democrats are equal. Some candidates, even in this straight-ticket era, run well ahead of their parties. And over the 10-year period between censuses, some voters switch parties, as in 2006 and 2008 and perhaps this year. Plus, how does a court judge that too many votes are wasted, and decide how much reverse cracking and packing is necessary to compensate for them?

More fundamentally, requiring courts to equalize each parties’ number of “wasted” votes amounts to saying that the Constitution requires proportionate representation of the sort used in many other countries. But the Constitution explicitly leaves the Congress free to decide how the states’ allocated seats are filled, and since 1842, Congress has chosen instead to require single-member districts with equal population.

Justice Elena Kagan, in a concurring opinion endorsed by the three other Democrat-appointed justices, takes the view that the Wisconsin plaintiffs could prevail in the lower court to which the chief justice remanded the case, if they present their case more strategically. She argues that the chief justice ignores precedents suggesting harm to a political party and not just to individual plaintiffs violates a First Amendment right, recognized by Kennedy in 2004, of freedom of association.

But like many Democratic politicians and commentators, Kagan overstates the evils of partisan district-drawing. “More effectively every day, that practice enables politicians to entrench themselves in power against the people’s will,” she writes.

This ignores the redistricting legerdemain of former Democratic Congressman Phillip Burton, whose hand-drawn redistricting plans gained more than a dozen House seats in California and other states in the 1970 and 1980 cycles. Liberals didn’t think gerrymandering imperiled democracy back then.

The Democrats’ current problem is not just that Republicans controlled districting in more states than Democrats after the 2000 and 2010 censuses. It’s also, as the court and the Wisconsin plaintiffs recognized, that Democratic voters are demographically clustered in central cities, sympathetic suburbs, and university towns, whereas Republican voters tend to be more evenly spread around.

A party whose voters are demographically clustered is at a disadvantage in any legislature with equal-population single-member districts. One solution for Democrats is to try to appeal beyond their current redoubts, as Bill Clinton did in the 1990s. That might even neutralize Republicans’ redistricting advantage after the 2020 Census.

Failing that, Gill v. Whitford suggests that the courts won’t be there to bail them out. Kagan and her colleagues may be eager to help, but they lack a fifth vote. And Roberts and four of his colleagues seem to be saying, “I would prefer not to” and that the equal-population requirement effectively limits political gains from partisan redistricting.

Related Content